Understanding globalisation impact on economic growth

As industries relocated to emerging markets, worries about job losses and reliance on other countries have grown amongst policymakers.



Critics of globalisation suggest it has resulted in the transfer of industries to emerging markets, causing job losses and greater reliance on other nations. In reaction, they propose that governments should move back industries by applying industrial policy. Nevertheless, this viewpoint does not acknowledge the dynamic nature of international markets and neglects the economic logic for globalisation and free trade. The transfer of industry had been mainly driven by sound economic calculations, particularly, companies look for cost-effective operations. There was clearly and still is a competitive advantage in emerging markets; they offer numerous resources, reduced manufacturing expenses, big consumer markets and favourable demographic trends. Today, major companies run across borders, tapping into global supply chains and reaping some great benefits of free trade as company CEOs like Naser Bustami and like Amin H. Nasser would probably aver.

History shows that industrial policies have only had minimal success. Various countries implemented different kinds of industrial policies to promote specific industries or sectors. Nevertheless, the outcome have usually fallen short of expectations. Take, for instance, the experiences of several Asian countries in the twentieth century, where extensive government involvement and subsidies by no means materialised in sustained economic growth or the desired transformation they imagined. Two economists evaluated the effect of government-introduced policies, including low priced credit to enhance manufacturing and exports, and compared industries which received help to those that did not. They concluded that during the initial phases of industrialisation, governments can play a constructive role in establishing companies. Although old-fashioned, macro policy, such as limited deficits and stable exchange prices, also needs to be given credit. However, data shows that helping one firm with subsidies tends to harm others. Additionally, subsidies allow the endurance of inefficient firms, making industries less competitive. Furthermore, whenever companies give attention to securing subsidies instead of prioritising innovation and efficiency, they remove resources from effective usage. Because of this, the entire financial aftereffect of subsidies on efficiency is uncertain and perhaps not good.

Industrial policy by means of government subsidies may lead other countries to retaliate by doing the same, which could affect the global economy, stability and diplomatic relations. This might be extremely risky because the general financial ramifications of subsidies on productivity continue to be uncertain. Despite the fact that subsidies may stimulate economic activity and produce jobs within the short run, in the future, they are more than likely to be less favourable. If subsidies are not accompanied by a range other steps that address efficiency and competition, they will likely hinder required structural changes. Hence, companies will end up less adaptive, which reduces development, as business CEOs like Nadhmi Al Nasr likely have noticed throughout their careers. It is therefore, truly better if policymakers were to concentrate on coming up with a method that encourages market driven growth instead of outdated policy.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *